j_spot the Journal of Social and Political
Thought

Volume One, No. 2 | June 2000


j_spot online edition ISSN 1481 8 5842


Contract Labour and Bondage in Andhra Pradesh (India)1

Wendy K. Olsen, PhD
Lecturer in Quantitative Development Economics, Graduate School
University of Bradford, UK

and

R.V. Ramana Murthy, PhD
Assistant Professor
NALSAR University of Law
Hyderabad, India

 
    Exploitation is a complex and multidimensional phenomenon, and although one particular type of exploitation, class exploitation, has a homogeneous measure under capitalism, this does not mean that such a measure can encapsulate either that form of exploitation, or exploitation in the richest and widest sense. (Hodgson, 1982: 216) The aim of this paper is to present our observations on a bonded labour system that currently exists in some districts of the state of Andhra Pradesh.  The empirical study throws light on the pervasiveness of unfree relations in this region.  Unequal, uneven development processes create diversity in labour relations.  It is important to study the variants of unfree labour in the context of India’s seasonal agriculture, its huge informal sector, and differences between rural and urban labour markets.  We present a case study of institutionalised bondage characteristic of villages in the drought-prone regions surrounding Mahabuubnagar town.  Over 100,000 rural labourers migrate seasonally from here to large public works sites elsewhere. The debt bondage of many such workers calls for a multi-pronged struggle against oppression in all its various forms.  This paper stresses the multidimensional nature of bondage, which has social, cultural, economic, and political aspects.  One implication is that unfreeness extends into the ‘private’ spheres of the home and personal relationships while also being a subject of highly public debate.  We end the paper with a challenge to future researchers to integrate domestic and family relationships into labour relations studies, rather than excluding or ignoring them.  Thus, like other recent contributions to the debate on bonded labour, ours offers both empirical and theoretical innovations (compare with Kapadia, 1995; Lerche, 1995; Brass, 1990). 

    Unfree labour relations have attracted considerable attention in the recent literature (Bhaduri, 1983; Patnaik and Dingwaney, 1985; Bharadwaj, 1985; Brass and van der Linden, 1998).  Some argued that unfree wage labour reflects not only underdeveloped labour markets, but also conjoint exploitation in interlocked markets (Srivastava, 1989) and an incomplete transition to the capitalist mode of production.  By contrast, Brass (1990, 1992, 1997a) and Miles (1987) take an opposing view that unfree relations are compatible with capitalism, comprising part of capitalists' assault on the autonomy and wages of labour.  Brass has argued that convict labour and indentured labour were subject to capitalist exploitation.  Analysis of the relations of production should be located in concrete historical context, and we find evidence that suggests bonded labour has roots in precapitalist structures (and ideology) and is used by capitalists in modern contexts.  Given the remarkable diversity in Indian agriculture, any generalisation from one case study would risk trivialising or oversimplifying the situation.  The present paper is concerned more to identify the concrete elements of exploitation and oppression in one case study.  The concept of interlocking markets is used to help grapple with the nature of class exploitation.  We also link interlocking markets to other institutions of oppression, such as caste and patriarchy.  The case study quantifies contracts at household and individual units of analysis while also broaching the qualitative question of inter-caste and intra-household social relations.  

    The paper is divided into four sections.  Firstly, a historical perspective on bondage in India is given and a brief review of literature is provided.  Secondly, we describe the origin and growth of Palamuuru contract labour, and present Ramana Murthy’s field observations on the working of the contract system in six villages of Andhra Pradesh.  Thirdly, we provide some analysis of exploitation in the system before concluding.  Our main innovation is to stress the dialectic between interpersonal modes of oppression and structural forms of oppression, thus extending the labour relations agenda to include interpersonal violence, sexual acts used to control or manipulate others, and other dyadic interactions that support and perhaps embody structural forms of oppression.  
     

    I. Introduction

    Debt-bondage in a historical perspective.  Slavery, with people referred to as dasa and dasi for male and female respectively, was widespread in ancient India, but the concept of dasi/dasa has been applied to a wide range of characteristics ranging from slave labour to caste-based subservience (Chakravarthy, 1985; Olsen, 1996).2  Kosambi (1956) described how slavery developed during the Aryan conquest of Dravidians and was later assimilated into the caste structure, with certain corporate groups (especially tribal peoples and harijans) relegated to agrestic slavery.  Dasis and dasas were frequently drawn into bondage in exchange for consumption loans.  Such debtors lacked the right to own means of production.  The associated ideology conferred the responsibility for redeeming obligations to the borrower’s descendants, making inter-generational bondage possible.  The intensely seasonal character of agriculture in several regions of the Indian subcontinent undermined the dry-season subsistence of tenants and agricultural labourers.  Many were induced into consumption loans at exorbitant interest rates.  Servitude was imposed until the principal was repaid, and until then, labour service constituted interest on the debt (Sarkar, 1985).  Such debt bondage, though changing in form, existed during the nineteenth century in every part of the Indian subcontinent (Saradamoni, 1973: 136, and 1980; Hjejle, 1967).  The colonial rulers created a new legal framework for this type of bondage with legislation such as the Workman's Breach of Contract Act of 1859 which made the violation of such contracts legally punishable.  It was then impossible for the bonded labourers to escape servitude.3 

    Thus the colonial rulers inherited specific forms of forced labour.  They introduced new variants such as indentured labour for plantations and for export to the Carribean and Fiji.  Indentured labour was only opposed by the Indian Congress in 1909, after it was a well entrenched practice that had underpinned huge flows of migrants.  However, the practice of indenturing labour continued for plantations and for public works within India even after that time.  Public works such as the building of roads, railway tracks, irrigation facilities, government buildings, military airports and barracks emerged as an important sector for which bonded labourers were recruited by contractors (Sarkar, 1985).  The terms of bondage in all these systems were not alien to the labourers.  Instead existing discourses of debt and obligation were adapted to create new variants.  The post-colonial state inherited many of the practices of its predecessors which facilitated blatant exploitation of workers in large-scale public works (Kerr, 1998).  Private contractors have thrived by exploiting cheap labour in several ways, such as: advancing wages and trapping people in bondage; transporting people to places of work alien to them; paying abysmally low wages; controlling the food and housing of seasonal migrants; imposing hazardous working and living conditions; and extracting phenomenal amounts of surplus value, thus reproducing the debt relations. 
     

    Interlocking markets and unfree labour.  A historical understanding of unfree labour relations in India shows that bondage has been conditioned by usury and denial of subsistence.  As others have pointed out, the imposition of everyday forms of oppression often operates through the institutions of caste.  Lerche (1998) offers a convincing case study of political tactics in two regions of Uttar Pradesh, where the caste basis of political action is having a profound effect on development trajectories (see also Lerche (1995) for a theorisation of the caste-class nexus).  In most contemporary Indian bonded-labour studies, surplus value exploitation and ‘non-economic’ forms of exploitation are mutually reinforcing elements, and their analytical links must be explored.  If a factor is non-economic but affects economic outcomes, then it is of course relevant in any analysis of the political economy.  Three schools of thought may be mentioned although these three are not necessarily mutually exclusive theoretical positions on all fronts.  The three that we will distinguish are the semi-feudalism thesis; the studies of bondage that see it occurring within capitalism; and the recent neo-institutional analyses. 

    In the literature on semi-feudalism in Indian agriculture, Bharadwaj (1985) brilliantly summarised the nature of forced commercialisation where people are circumscribed by the interlocking of credit, output and labour markets.  She argued that underdevelopment of one market can mute the development of other markets.  A dominant party conjointly exploits the weaker party in two or more markets, and the weaker party in the exchange loses the option to exercise choice in other markets due to their commitment in one.  The label semi-feudalism was applied by Bhaduri (1973, 1983) to this sort of situation.  Basu (1983, 1986) offered a mathematized version of a similar argument.  Bhaduri was pessimistic about the prospects for capitalist growth, and he developed mathematical models of class interaction to show that it is possible for semi-feudal landlords to inhibit technological change if they find it in their own interest to focus on extracting surplus rather than allowing the overall productivity of the land they control to increase.  Bhaduri’s 1977 paper explores the role of usury in such a scenario.  A number of case studies that take this strand of theory as a starting point have shown capitalist landlords to be taking diverse strategies in different regions of India (Olsen, 1996; Harriss-White, 1996; and Harriss, 1982).  Some academic observers would not accept a simple characterisation of Indian agriculture as semi-feudal, semi-capitalist although all the rural studies do show landlords and landlord-moneylenders using social power as well as economic position to extract surplus value.  The semi-feudalism thesis per se sees the function of landlords’ power as holding back agriculture (Bhaduri, 1983), but the empirical studies mentioned above show rapid technical change interacting with changing social and economic power relations over time.  The social relations do not necessarily hold back technical change. 

    Nevertheless there has been a consensus about the semi-feudalism thesis among a large number of marxist writers in India (Bhaduri, 1973, 1977, 1983; Patnaik, 1983; Bharadwaj, 1985; Rao, R.S., 1995; Balagopal, 1988; Ramachandran, 1990).  These writers have attempted to stress forms of unfreedom that exist in agrarian relations to distinguish the ‘free’ wage labour in the classic double sense in capitalism i.e. free of means of production (nonpeasants), and free to sell their labour power.  The use of the term semi-feudalism aimed to stress the incomplete growth of capitalist relations between capitalist landlords and labourers and the inability of capitalist relations to eliminate social modes of oppression. 

    Partly as a result of his own findings, and partly in order to improve current strategies for social change, Brass has argued that it is a mistake even to refer to semi-feudalism (or especially feudalism) in the context of analysing contemporary unfree labour.  Brass’s concern is that the semi-feudalism thesis focuses too much attention on individual landlords or their class, instead of focusing on the developing capitalist system as a whole.  Brass’s 1990 case study, based in Haryana, showed that unfree labour exists even in ‘developed’ regions.  This point is also made by Lerche and Kapadia.  Brass called this phenomenon ‘deproletarianisation’, and argued that such labour relations can exist within the capitalist mode of production.  Bondage may even increase, or its forms proliferate, in the context of the constant aggression of capitalists on labour.  Brass argues that free wage labour in the classic double sense has never existed anywhere in history (1997a).  Capital always invents and employs various forms of unfreedom to control and manage labour.  Even in the most industrialised countries, labour is not free in an absolute sense.  Therefore, he argues that the forms of unfreedom among attached farm servants in India are misconstrued if described as feudal remnants.  Instead deproletarianisation is a strategy of capital.  

    However, in Indian agriculture the prevalence of attached labour (in the sense of farm servants) has declined considerably, as confirmed by Jodhka (1994), and especially so in the more irrigated and commercialised regions.  Venkateswarlu (1997) makes a similar finding for coastal Andhra Pradesh.  Attached farm labourer relationships are still found in dry and backward regions.  One report on bonded labour in Medak District, another dry area of Andhra Pradesh, noted the widespread prevalence of attached labour (Subrahmaniam et al, 1994), putting the figure at 500,000 with bonded labour among them as 13,000.  From the interplay of the semi-feudalism thesis and the deproletarianisation thesis we draw two conclusions.  Firstly the forms of labour relations are diverse across India, and one therefore expects the dynamic trajectories arising from them to be varied.  Secondly, the labels used for classes and power groups in analytical theories (e.g. semi-feudal landlords; capitalist class; workers) are potent in themselves when they become integrated into political action.  Instead of making a conscious choice between competing labels for social classes, it may be important to recognise diverse forms of exploitation—– between castes; between genders; patriarchal exploitation of the young; and class exploitation.  Each of these forms in turn interacts with the others.  A social relations approach rejects the dualism offered by the Brass-vs.-Bhaduri debate in favour of integrating feminist insights with marxist theories.  A similar integration is achieved by Kapadia (1992, 1995) in her gem-cutting and agricultural-labouring case studies.  We also see a variety of social structures stressed by Kalpagam (1994: chs. 1-2), who is analysing women’s informal-sector work.  The social relations approach is also consistent with the analysis offered by Kabeer (1994).  Brass himself explains that kin relations and gender are integrated into many unfree-labour analyses (1997b: 38).  However Brass ignores the problem that the conceptions of ‘worker’ and ‘labour’ used by most contributors to Free and Unfree Labour: The Debate Continues are anathema to feminists who wish to transcend the dualism of productive-vs.-reproductive work (e.g. Himmelweit (1995) who criticizes the assumption of a work-nonwork divide).4  For transformative politics, it is important to identify explicitly oppressive modes of social behaviour, both within and between households.  

    A third school of thought lies out side of the political-economy tradition.  Neoclassical economists such as Srinivasan (1989) have examined the labour-credit linkage.  These economists analyse contractual debt bondage as risk-averting behaviour of the bonded labourer, who is assumed to be a rational maximiser of his/her utility in light of the conditions they live in.  By accepting a year long contract, one reduces the transactions costs of finding alternative employment avenues and one avoids unemployment.  Unemployment would be worse than the contract which guarantees some work and food for a person and their children.  The oppression is taken to be an acceptable cost of reducing risk.  Such an approach is shallow in its understanding of the nature of bondage and poverty.  Authors in this tradition claim to be more objective than the marxists.  However Olsen (1998) has stressed the subjective positioning of such authors and the specific norms that are embedded in their claim that bondage contracts must be efficient.  The claim is also functionalist since research on transactions costs and risk aversion could not falsify the claim that all contracts are efficient.  Contracts are seen merely to function to keep the capitalist economy working efficiently.  Neoclassical economics has been evolving from demand-supply models, through transactions-costs analysis, to information economics, and now centres on the ‘new information economics’ which we have called neo-institutionalism.  Hoff and Stiglitz (1990) give a presentation of the theory, while Hodgson (1993) distinguishes the old and new institutionalisms.  However the apolitical economists still underplay the role of local politics and social power in the development of labour relations.  Caste, gender and household dynamics play no role in these models.  In common with methodological individualism generally, the new institutional economics has an implicit gender bias and a claim to value-freeness, whereas the political economists are prepared to make their normative positions explicit and to open them up to debate.  These epistemological differences help to explain why both of the political economy schools are so open to the introduction of feminist ideas, whereas the neo-institutionalists are not. 
     

    Exploring the underlying social structure.  Much of the marxist debate on unfree labour has been conducted on narrow class lines ignoring other institutions of oppression such as patriarchy and caste.5  In order to consider such factors explicitly along with class exploitation, a useful starting point is the one suggested by Hodgson (1982: 208-216).  He classifies exploitation into: i) exploitation through bargaining power; ii) exercising authority to force someone to do somethingespecially 'work' but taking work to include unpaid and ‘unproductive’ services; iii) corporeal exploitation through violence, restriction of movement, and sexual advances; and iv) value exploitation through the appropriation of surplus value in the labour process.  Such a division might widen the scope of analysis from the narrow economic/monetised/public realm to a wider landscape involving more subtle and private forms of oppression.  All the forms may be found co-existing.  They are interlinked and are often mutually reinforcing.  Workers’ subjective understanding of their ‘proper’ role(s) can help to entrench exploitative relationships, quite apart from the deliberate exercise of power through explicit intentional action.  The converse is that changes at a subjective level may reverberate upon the real social relations, such as class relations. 

    One can also try to understand the partial embodiment of hierarchical social relationships in the body itself.  The musculature, body size, eating habits, ability to withstand outdoor work, and various manual skills that workers acquire, are all examples of bodily traits that both reflect and perpetuate the current distribution of work.  Fay (1987) argued in support of this thesis.  He warned that critical social scientists should understand and study embodiment, as it places limits on the immediate prospects for change in labour relations.  Ultimately the purpose of his and our analysis is to guide activists in planning effective strategies for change. 

    Some forms of oppression are divided into various modes in Table 1.  As Hodgson proposed, we have four modes of exploitation: bargaining; corporeal; authority; and value.  In addition we can separate interpersonal forms from general structural locations that create the conditions for apparently anonymous exploitation (first row versus second row).  For instance, any bond or contract with outstanding loan obligations reduces the bargaining power of the worker.  The employers may restrict workers’ physical mobility, thereby denying access to information about alternatives to bondage.  This is particularly important in places where the labour market is underdeveloped, with high transactions costs and few employers.  Authority structures arising out of the institutions of caste and patriarchy (and thus with roots far back in history) limit people’s verbal negotiating freedom, especially for women.  The ideologies of caste and gender roles place a personal price on breaches of behavioural norms.  Similarly the caste structure claims dominance and high status for the high castes and thus underpins the unequal power relations with labourers.  

     

    Table 1: Modes of Oppression Within Patriarchal Capitalism
    (Some Examples)
     
     
      Bargaining  Corporeal  Authority  Value 
    Dyadic - between people  deals, contracts, bonds, indebtedness, submissiveness, illiteracy  violence, immobilisation, abuse, rape, sexual advances  imposing authority as husbands, fathers, elders of both genders, upper-caste employers  transfer of surplus value in the form of profit from exchange or production; includes unpaid overtime and services 
    Structural - embedded, systemic, and impersonal  poverty, lack of subsistence, esp. seasonally or during drought; ignorance of alternatives; alienation from home village; lack of unionisation  hunger, weakness, debilitation, and ill health constraining and influencing action -- embodied inequality  presumption of caste subordination; traditional roles of breadwinner and housewife; patronage  exchanges that appear ‘free’ but which involve indirect exploitation through exchange, e.g. the pricing of the food and health care in labour camps 
     

    Underlying the edifice described above is the class structure.  At the same time, patriarchy is a separate dimension that imposes an unequal gendered division of labour within households as well as in public arenas.  We define patriarchy as the subordination of women as a gender to men as a gender.  It is not independent of class, but rather interacts with it; in all we have here several social divisions that all reinforce unequal access to property (Agarwal, 1998) and the denial of some people’s control over resources, including their own bodies. 
     

    II. Case Study of Palamuuru Contract Labour

    Growth and origin.  Mahabubnagar district in the state of Andhra Pradesh in India is an unindustrialised, chronically drought-prone, and unirrigated region now popular for Palamuuru labour for six public works.6  It is useful to glance over certain statistics of the region.  The district has more poverty than other districts in the state, according to 1987-88 estimates.  Sixty-five percent of the people live below poverty (Radhakrishna et al, 1987).  For the year 1993, eighty percent of the district was officially declared as drought affected.  Field work was done by Ramana Murthy in 1991 and 1994.  The region has a history of drought throughout the last four decades or more.  Drought has led to a massive decline in the area under tank irrigation i.e. dams with reservoirs of varying sizes, which is the principal source of water for crops (see Table 2).7  The net sown area under all principal crops has declined over thirty percent in the past two decades.  Similarly, fallows have increased and rainfall often deviates far below the historic normal level.  Cultivation is possible only for three to four months in kharif season (August to December), leaving a slack season of over eight months.  Such regions have for centuries provided cheap labourers who migrate seasonally for survival and who will work for extremely low wages. 

      

    Table 2: Land Use, Irrigation and Rainfall in Mahabubnagar District 
    (in thousands of acres)
     
    Year  Net Sown Area  Area Under Canals  Area Under Tanks  Net Irrigated Area 
    1961  936,300  10,535  21,955  110,064 
    1971  1,053,713  22,430  25,730  108,753 
    1981  919,707  24,090  50,942  126,522 
      Source: Compiled from various Statistical Abstracts, Published by Government of Andhra Pradesh, Bureau of Economics and Statistics, Hyderabad.

    Mobilising forced labour for public works such highways, railway tracks, irrigation projects, etc., had been a common colonial practice (Kerr, 1998).  Evidence suggests similar recruitments of labour originated in Mahabubnagar district.  For instance, since 1934 labour groups were used to build the Nizamsagar dam by the Nizam government.8  

    The construction of Nizamsagar dam involved a massive need for labour both skilled and unskilled. . . especially excavation of earth, blasting, blasting rock in foundation, quarrying stone for machinery and miscellaneous.  The labour for these works had been imported from dominions including Raichur, Gulbarga, Mahabubnagar, Nalgonda and Karimnagar. . . Palmuuries coming from Mahabubnagar did a good work at excavation, especially earth work at ground level. . . The method of recruiting the labourers is mainly through the department by forwarding advances ranging from Rs. [rupees] 5 to Rs. 10 per year for the gangs willing to come. (H.E.H. Nizam Dominion, 1939).

    The existence of vettichakiri (one word for bonded labour in Telugu language) may have facilitated labour mobilisation by the village administrations in the Nizam dominion.  The practice of engaging contract labour for all major public works, particularly dams, canals highways, etc., continues unhindered even until today.  One sees the tenders for government contracts to organise large-scale building sites (labour and inputs) in most Indian newspapers.  Thus ironically the bonded labour discussed here as existing within capitalist patriarchy is actually primarily sponsored and funded by the Indian government. 

    The introduction of large-scale irrigation in the post-independence period turned this region into a source of cheap labour with a remarkable network of middlemen.  Such a relentless form exploitation in the region, has received surprisingly little attention in the literature on labour.  Walker and Ryan (1990), writing about several well-funded long-term village studies of which one was based in a palamuur labour village, say very little about it.  Nor do any official statistics exist to capture the extent of it, as the Indian Census and National Sample Survey have ignored seasonal migration.  However, several researchers have noted a significant level of presence of seasonally bonded labour in at least eight out of twenty-four mandils of the District (Ravinder, 1989; Ramana Murthy, 1991; Reddy, 1990; Rao, Usha, 1994).  The migrants from Mahabubnagar district can be classified into three groups: firstly, those who migrate for seasonal agriculture work in cotton, paddy and sugarcane growing areas; secondly, those who migrate to Hyderabad and other cities to work in the construction industry, usually also seasonally; and thirdly, those who migrate on contract work.  See for details Ramana Murthy (1991) and Usha Rao (1994).  In Mahabubnagar District alone local experts estimate that at least 150,000 people go away to migration works every year.  Of these, about 50,000 (one third) are thought to be bonded labourers. 
     

    How the Palamuuru contract system works.  There are two ranks of middlemen: group maistries (labour contractors) and maistries (supervisors).  (We use the gender-specific term middlemen, although it is possible to have women taking on this role.9  All the intermediaries in this particular study area in 1991 and 1994 were male.)  Construction companies place an order for the requisite labour force and advance a mutually agreed amount of money.  Each group maistry patronises a team of maistries, each of whom actually mobilises a group of 20 to 30 labourers.  The company forwards some money to the group maistry, who in turn passes some on to the maistry, after retaining his commission.  The usual terms of the contract in both 1991 and 1994 were 8 to 9 months’ work, 12 hours work each day, a holiday for a fortnight, a pack of cheap cigarettes (beedies) for a man every week, and hair oil and food for the labourer and his/her dependent children.  The advance was Rs. 2000 per worker in 1991 for an eight month contract for a man or a woman.  Nominally, this was thought of as a monthly wage of Rs. 200 and provision of free food at the work site.  Two days’ wages are deducted for a day's absence (one for the day's wage and the other for the free food).  If a worker cannot work continuously, and falls sick, any medical expenses are deducted from the wage and counted as debt.  Workers renew their contracts yearly, sometimes because they cannot redeem their loans and sometimes in order to obtain further loans.  For labourers coming from landless and small peasant households struggling to subsist, the maistries are practically monopoly creditors and monopsony buyers of their labour power in the absence of alternative sources of credit and employment.  Such contract labourers hail from the lower castes, enabling the middlemen to command enormous control in enforcing the contract, restricting their mobility at labour camps, and so on.  The maistries have to guard the labourers to keep them from going away as their money is locked up in the investment.  Accounts are settled with the higher-up contractors only at the end of the period.  The respondents in the field study reported that many of the women suffer sexual exploitation, and that children are used for numerous unpaid services. 

    The construction companies in this way save a phenomenal amount of money, by paying much less than market wages on the one hand, and extracting four to six hours overtime without pay on the other.10  For example, simple calculations reveal that each labourer otherwise entitled to more than Rs. 10,000 for eight months work is given only Rs. 2000, the remaining being shared by the company and the middlemen.11  A maistry takes a gross commission of Rs. 30,000 and a group maistry Rs. 100,000 for one contract.12  As these middlemen invest money initially and settle accounts with the company only at the end of the year, they are highly exploitative.  The company has no formal or written relation with the labourers.  It is the maistry's responsibility to supervise, to extract work, and to settle the accounts as well as to settle disputes.  Almost all the labourers are illiterate and rely totally on the maistry in settling accounts (Ramana Murthy, 1991). 

    The Palamuuru contract system violates the legal rights of workers.  It contravenes the Bonded Labour Abolition Act 1976, the Interstate Migrant Workmen Act (Regulation of Employment and Conditions of Service) 1979 and the Minimum Wages Act 1974 of the Government of India.13  Consider for instance the case of Chenayya, 28 years old, of Palem village: 

    The maistry and group maistry were cruel.  They beat my wife when we said we wanted to go to Hyderabad for work.  I have some loans to Rs. 7000.  The maistry does not relieve me from contract work.14 

    Although the legislative acts are so liberally framed, with victims not having to produce any written evidence, they are difficult to enforce because the people have little alternative employment.  The number of these contract labourers can be no fewer than 50,000 people (4.9 percent of the number of ‘main workers’ as described in the Census of the District of Mahabuubnagar).  Several other researchers have confirmed this degree of prevalence, for example, Usha Rao (1994) and Ravinder (1989). 
     

    Field observations.  We present the observations made during the field investigations (as part of a study on rural migration in the region) in August 1991 in five villages in three revenue divisions (mandals) and during another visit in October 1994 in these villages and one more village.  The information presented here pertains to 49 contract labour households, which had in total 162 migrants.  Some of these households were re-visited in October 1994.  Information was elicited from the respondents using both questionnaires and informal inquiries.  Four out of the six villages have exclusively contract labour migration, and two villages have casual labour migration as well.  Inquiries were made about the socioeconomic background of the migrant labourers, the terms of their contracts, and why they went.  We present a summary of these and some profiles of labourers before moving to the analysis section. 

    The villages were essentially poorly irrigated, semi-arid areas with red spongy soils having a low water retention capacity.  Village tanks are the principal source of irrigation, supported by wells, irrigating less than one third of cultivated land (see Table 3).  The main crops grown are paddy, jowar (sorghum), bajra (millet), groundnut and castor bean, as well as other pulses.  Low irrigation in the villages limits commercial agriculture to those households with good soil and/or water supply.  

     

    Table 3: Land Use and Irrigation in the Sample Villages
    According to the 1981 Census
     
    Village 
    Area (Hectares) 
    Percent of Land Cultivated 
    Percent of Land Cultivable Waste 
    Percent Forest Land 
    Percent Irrigated by Any Source 
    K. Nagula 
    1989 
    55% 
    1% 
    10% 
    9% 
    Banala 
    925 
    78 
    17 
    22 
    11 
    Balmur 
    2160 
    58 
    17 
    Palem 
    769 
    84 
    30 
    Pangal* 
    2319 
    44 
    17 
    13 
    Mohammed Pur* 
    836 
    80 
    Source: Census of India, 1981. 

    * Note: These two villages have casual out-migration, whereas the others have exclusively Palamuuru contract out-migration on a seasonal basis.

    Most of the poor practiced subsistence agriculture in the kharif season and migrated for their livelihood in the slack season.  Declining agriculture had forced many people from middle and upper peasant households out of agriculture.  Some such men had taken up the role of maistry and group maistry, which enabled them to exercise the traditional ways of controlling labourers under modern economic conditions. 

    Six out of the 162 contract labourers were aged above 45 years, and these reported 25 years of contract labour.  These people had worked on the Bhakranangal dam (circa 1951), Hirakud (circa 1959), Nagarjunasagar dam (circa 1961), and various steel plants, railway lines, and road constructions since then (Ramana Murthy, 1991).  Fifty-nine labourers between 35-45 years of age had been working since they were teenagers.  Fifty-eight people aged between 25-35 and 37 people aged between 10-15 years were working in the ongoing Narmada Dam (Madhya Pradesh)-Sardar Sarovar (Gujarat) project funded by the World Bank.  The health of the migrant workers deteriorates during the contract work, and many became unfit for this work by the age of 45 years. 

    Contract labourers primarily hail from landless agricultural labour households (22 percent) and marginal and small farm households (67 percent), as shown in Table 4.  We have classified households owning less than 0.5 hectare of land as marginal; 0.5 to 2 hectares as small farms; and 2-4 hectares as semi-middle farms.  With the recent distribution of waste land to landless households, the number of marginal households has risen.  The caste-wise background of households having contract labourers showed 40 percent belonging to the scheduled castes, 15 percent to the scheduled tribes, and 45 percent to the backward castes.  One household belonged to a so-called ‘forward’ caste. 

     

    Table 4: Age, Sex and Class Distribution in the Sample Study
     
    Type of House-hold 
    Number of Households in Sample 
    Number of Contract Migrants 
    Age Distribution of Migrants 
    Gender 
         
    10 to 15 Yrs 
    >15 Years 
    Male 
    Female 
    I. Landless  11  35  30  17  18 
    II. Marginal Farms  19  58  17  41  26  24 
    III. Small Farms  14  52  19  33  37  14 
    IV. Semi-Middle Farms  17  16  14 
    Total:  49  162  42  120  94  58 
    Source: Ramana Murthy, field data, 1991.

    The gross farm incomes from the subsistence agriculture of these households were estimated in per capita terms to be Rs. 332; Rs. 1866; and Rs. 3970 in 1991 for the marginal, small and semi-middle farms respectively (Table 5).  When the imputed costs of family labour were deducted, some households were shown to have negative net income.15  Needless to say, most of these people live below the official poverty line. 

     

    Table 5: Income and Debt Among Sampled Contract Labour Households
     
    Type of Household 
    Average Land Holding (Acres) 
    Average Gross Farm Income 
    Per Capita Gross Income, Rupees, including Wages 
    Average Household Debt 
    I. Landless 
    1195 
    3831 
    II. Marginal Farms 
    1.5 
    332 
    1575 
    3256 
    III. Small Farms 
    4.1 
    1586 
    1450 
    3839 
    IV. Semi-Middle Farms 
    9.1 
    3970 
    1206 
    6482 
    Source: Ramana Murthy, field data, 1991. 

    Note: Per capita gross income per annum was estimated as wage income in the case of landless labour and wages plus farm income in the case of the land-owning households.  No income was imputed for own-labour on farms in the latter cases.

     
    Table 6: Sources of Debt
     
    Type of Household 
    Indebtedness By Source of Loans
    (Percent Owing): 
     
    . . . to the Maistry 
    . . . to the Moneylender 
    . . . to the Bank 
    . . . to Relatives and Friends 
    I. Landless 
    56 
    32 
    12 
    II. Marginal Farms 
    48 
    21 
    16 
    15 
    III. Small Farms 
    32 
    31 
    21 
    16 
    IV. Semi-Middle Farms 
    39 
    21 
    28 
    12 
    Source: Ramana Murthy, field data, 1991. 

    Note: The various debts of households were aggregated and divided by the number of households to arrive at average household debt of different farm size classes.

     
    Reasons for accepting advances.  The contract labourers got loans of Rs. 2,000 each and had debts of up to Rs. 10,000 per household.  The average outstanding debt for each category of household is shown to be several thousand Rupees (Table 5).  The estimated farm incomes were below the poverty line, and thus below subsistence.  Most loans were taken from maistries, and these were nominally interest free.  As one respondent, Ballayya, 35 years old, said:   My father took a loan of Rs. 500 15 years ago on my name in order to marry my sister.  Debts increased as we took further loans when famine hit the village.16  As the old loans being repaid through my labour, further loans were taken for the reasons of my marriage house construction and purchase of some land.  Today my wife and I still go for the contract work to repay some outstanding loans.  My daughter is growing to marriage age.  Who will give a loan without pledging any collateral?  The maistry has agreed to give Rs. 3000 in the next season.17 

    The loans that were obtained from moneylenders constituted 30 per cent of total debt and were charged at interest rates of 48 to 60 percent per annum.  Most of these loans, other than those incurred during the contract, were taken for the purposes of marriage, construction of houses, agricultural investments or medical expenses.  The erratic rainfall and declining ground water also drew small peasants into indebtedness, as seen in the case below: 

    Kistayya (38 years old) held 6 acres land jointly with his brother.  Both invested Rs. 30,000 on a well to grow groundnut in 1987 by borrowing Rs. 10,000 from a rural bank and Rs. 15,000 from moneylenders at a 48 per cent per year interest rate.  Two years later the well dried up and he had to take an advance from a maistry for subsistence.  The family has an outstanding loan of Rs. 11,000.18  

    Similarly in another instance, 

    Golla Chandrayya took a loan from a bank under the Integrated Rural Development Programme (IRDP) of Rs. 5500 in 1989.  All the sheep he bought died for lack of veterinary care.  He repaid the first instalment of Rs. 1000 by taking an advance of Rs. 4000 from the maistry.  The rest of this money was spent repaying consumption loans taken from relatives for subsistence.  He has a fresh debt of Rs. 600 incurred in Rajasthan on contract work.19 

    Couples were preferred by maistries and were given larger total loans in case of need, being seen as reliable.  The status of female migrants was appalling, as the advance money given on their labour, is given to her husband or father.  These women scarcely have any control over their earnings.  As Venkata Laxmi (29 years) narrates, 

    The men would take our money and often squander it on liquor.  They beat us if we demand the money.  We work hard on fields as wage labour and save money for our needs.  The contract work is so hard.  They make us run all the time.  We have to keep pace with the concrete mixing machines without a respite.  Any good looking women can never escape sexual harassment.  But what to do, it is a question of survival.20 

    Maistries hailed from land-owning households, and in the past mostly came from the upper castes, particularly Reddies.  In 1991 and 1994, though, group maistries were encouraging maistries from all castes, as observed in one village.  But still labourers of the various castes, including scheduled caste people, did not work under a lower caste maistry, since they do not take food from them.  That the middlemen had made money was indicated by their assets and consumption patterns, such as owning a tractor and a colour television and getting urban convent education for their children.  For instance  

    Ram Reddy (42 years old) has been a maistry for the past decade.  He has 25 acres of land, but only 5 acres is cultivated due to lack of water.  He owns a pucca (solid) house and educates his two sons in a nearby town.  He shied away from revealing his earnings but felt it was the group maistry who made a lot of money.  According to him, he takes the risk of picking up the labourers, organising them, supervising them, and bearing all sorts of headaches in managing them.  He revealed his ambition of becoming a group maistry.  He is trying to make a deal with a company.21 

    The migration histories of the sample contract labour migrants are testimonies to the existence of the contract system for more than three decades.  Most of these people had worked in more than six states of India each. 
     

    Instability and change in migration pattern.  There is a considerable instability in migration patterns seen during our visits.  In two villages, people were migrating as casual labour to Hyderabad city, yet in these villages the Palamuuru contract system had been prevalent.  The transition to casual labour migration has been encouraged by several factors.  These villages had better irrigation facilities, compared to the four contract-labour villages, and even compared with the surrounding villages.  The people’s personal knowledge of Hyderabad city since the early 1980s had enabled them to wriggle out of the grip of the contract system and the middlemen.  However, this has only solved the immediate subsistence problem inasmuch as they continue to sojourn between their village and the city.  They did not avail themselves of any provisions in the city, such as ration cards or education of children.  With their incomplete integration into the urban economy and a faint hope of improvement in the condition of the home village, they shuttled back and forth between rural poverty and urban poverty. 
     

    III. Analysis

    Interlinked modes of exploitation.  The Mahabubnagar agriculture is typically characterised by intermittent spells of drought throwing up a peculiar situation.  Maistries and group maistries, whilst growing into a class of employers, have begun to emerge as monopolistic agents in the credit markets that trap the hapless poor.  They are also monopsonistic agents for employment in a virtually paralysed village economy.  This situation has led to interlocked markets for credit and labour.  Indeed, the interlocking through personalised contracts creates a monopoly with a differentiated product (the relationship).  The migrant labourers’ situation is a variant on Bhaduri’s model (1973, 1983).  In his general model of landlord-tenant relations, the rent-cum-interest on land is fixed by the landlord such that the tenants’ earnings are less than subsistence.  They then borrow from the monopolistic lender (landlord), hence the interlocking of modes of exploitation.  In a similar way, the migrants’ wage plus food is fixed at a level below subsistence, so they keep borrowing.  However, the maistries’ commission rate is so high that even the interest on their investment can be covered without explicitly charging labourers interest. 

    As expressed by the migrants, the labour relations gain acceptability for the reasons akin to those for accepting attached labour.  

    Bakkayya (25 years old) is an attached labourer and middle peasant, for an annual wage Rs. 1800, without food, paid in advance.  Days of absence were accounted at the rate of the local daily wage, and had to be redeemed through labour.  Two years back due to severe drought his employer relieved him of work.  Then he has taken an advance from a maistry and worked for one season.  He did not go again since then. He owes some Rs. 400 to the maistry, but has not been pressed for the repayment.  But the respondent felt if his landlord cannot provide more money he may be forced to take further loans from the maistry.22  

    The legitimisation process is facilitated by the caste system, as lower caste persons are expected to conform to their subjugation.  Lerche has begun to theorise the caste-class linkage in a way that differs from the purely class-based Marxist approach of Byres (1981) and Brass (1995).  For many, repudiation of a ‘patron’ would only worsen their situation.  Maistries from lower castes prove no better.  Although their strategies of controlling and oppressing differ slightly from the others', they lead similarly to value-exploitation.  The ongoing social processes of dependence and resistance may be understood better through a typology that contrasts interpersonal elements with those based on structural locations (see Table 1).  
      

    Oppression through reducing bargaining power:  

    i) Dyadic: the maistries have a grip if there is an outstanding loan.  The debts incurred by migrant family members restrict their bargaining abilities in seeking either a contract or escape.  Fixing workers into contract labour overtime restricts their access to information on labour markets elsewhere, further weakening their bargaining abilities.  

    ii) Structural: Many workers are so bankrupt and destitute that they have few options other than working for the maistry.  However, those with some irrigated land and information on labour markets are in a better position, and more of the casual labour migrants come from such households (Ramana Murthy, 1991: 90-95).  Workers who have relatives in cities are also in a better position to bargain with potential employers, since they can if necessary migrate to cities and look for work.   
      

    Oppression through the body (corporeal):  

    i) Dyadic: within a contract, the employer can control food intake, water supply, housing conditions, and to some extent the health care of the worker.  Palamuuru labourers, debilitated by the relentless work, depend on their employer for further loans to maintain and improve their health.  Occasional beatings and verbal abuse of those people who disobey the employer or who try to leave without repaying cause other workers to be self-disciplined labourers.  There may be strong gender differences in the nature of corporeal oppression and these require further research.  

    ii) Structural: For many women the patriarchal system denies them wages for domestic labour, and then lets their menfolk control the wages they earn as employees.  Women are expected to accept a lack of personal spending money; domestic violence; and coercion from employers.  Sexual harassment of a woman who does physical outdoor work is seen by some people as being the woman’s fault, since she shows herself in public.  The resulting embarassment or illicit sexual liaisons may be seen as oppressive to women even though the people involved might think it perfectly acceptable.  In addition, female workers have to care for and feed children as well as themselves while working (in fields or at construction sites).  Men don’t have this disadvantage, merely because they are men in a patriarchal society.  Most women’s mobility is more restricted than men’s, not only because of the presence of children but also by the understanding that they are responsible for the home/hut/tent and therefore do not have a right to leave it without permission.  These implicit constraints on women's mobility limit their ability to secure information and improve their bargaining power.  Norms about the domestic roles of women cannot be neglected in considering their lives as contract migrant workers.  
      

    Oppression through authority:  

    i) Dyadic: During the Palamuuru contract, as described above, the maistry has control over the movements and activities of the workers.  Their control derives not only from the debt or contract, but also from class/caste identities and traditions of respect and servility that may operate between a maistry and a worker.  In addition, a female worker may face the authority of her husband, brother, father, or mother-in-law who may force her to work and possibly also deprive her of control over her earnings.  Children themselves are subject to authority of the elders, and in contract labour families, kids became contract labourers in their own right from the age of ten onwards (Ramana Murthy, 1991).  

    ii) Structural: Habits and traditions of inter-caste behaviour may not require any explicit enforcement to remain extremely powerful.  Self-regulated submissive behaviour is embedded in the caste system, where workers of lower castes do not eat food in front of an upper caste maistry, may hesitate to touch them, keep a distance from them, do not enter their home/hut or their cooking area, and so on.  Employers hailing from the upper castes may have high political, social and economic status.  Furthermore, when going in public the worker may face ridicule and ostracism if they decide to flout the dictates of the maistry.  The combination of class and caste factors militates against the person’s consciousness in fighting the employer.  By contrast, workers who stay within the system become a part of a cohesive group serving one maistry and are subject to pressure to conform to the behaviour of that group.  
      

    Value exploitation:  

    i) Dyadic: It is possible to measure the gross profits reeled in by each maistry as the difference between their revenue and their wage bill to get a rough indicator of value-exploitation per worker and its variations.  However this account will not cover the additional indirect exploitation undertaken by the construction company by underpayment and the overtime without pay.  Handling the profits at local and higher levels requires more information and a clear conceptualisation of profit and surplus value.  Firstly, input costs on the employer's side should be allowed for.  Secondly, the profits realised by the contractor’s firm may increase over time after the contract itself is finished.  A dyadic approach to estimating the rate of value-exploitation would suffer from the tendency to focus too heavily on direct relations of production (the labour relation) and to ignore indirect exploitation through exchange.   

    Nevertheless, even crude estimates, as given earlier, can have a powerful effect on consciousness since many workers may be unaware of the extent of exploitation.  Another area ignored by the calculation of value exploitation between employer and employee is the extent of unpaid labour that is being done by women and children (and perhaps also men, if they go to collect firewood or to get water).  In addition to cooking, watching children, cleaning, and doing other work aimed at reproduction of the labour force, women also provide sexual services (by choice or duress; for the husband or for the maistry).  It was difficult to gather information on this important area without long periods of residence, but we have begun to develop an agenda for local research and activism.  

    ii) Structural: Perhaps more important than the pairwise rate of value-exploitation is the fact that these labourers seem to have a buffer between themselves and capitalist exploitation.  They would have to fight off the maistries and group maistries before they could wage a class struggle with the ultimate employers or even find out who they are.  The fight against parasitic middlemen would perhaps save them from bondage only to become free wage labourer in the usual capitalist sense (Miles, 1987).  New forms of unfreedom may also emerge, as Brass contends, yet at least the current forms might disappear through the growing consciousness of the people.  Such a radical consciousness is severely hindered by caste divisions and kinship loyalties (as Brass himself has pointed out, Brass (1986)).  

    The recognition of modes of exploitation in interlocked markets is useful in two ways – both for innovative research, as mentioned above, and for innovative strategies for action.  The legal abolition of bonded labour has not succeeded in freeing bonded workers, though it may have had some effects on their consciousness.  Twice in separate instances described by respondents, Palamuuru contract labour were declared as bonded labour and released—once by the Lathur District collector at the request of a local voluntary agency, and once more recently in Ranga Reddy District.  There is no evidence of their rehabilitation.  These people will, in all probability, have now re-entered contract work.  One can argue for the formation of labour markets with generalised rights, yet continue the proletarian struggle for the reduction of value-exploitation and the elimination of oppression.  One author has gone so far as to include among the definitional characteristics of ‘free wage labourers’ the proviso that they must have the genuine right to withdraw their labour through quitting or going on strike (Grossman, 1997).  Grossman’s study, based in South Africa, illustrates how within capitalism the ‘freedom’ of workers is perpetually constrained.  It also shows that ‘freedom’ is a social construct which can be used in many contexts to represent various situations as acceptable.  At least one author has questioned the free/unfree dichotomy itself, arguing that it sets up a spectrum that lends itself to liberal and not to progressive values (Prakash, 1990).  The debate over unfree labour is not a matter of ascertaining facts, but rather one of spreading an action-oriented awareness of exploitative social relationships.  

    One research proposal arising out of the rather disturbing evidence above is to explore modes of resistance as well as modes of oppression along the two dimensions shown in Table 1.  In this way the analysis presented in this paper moves beyond Hodgson’s original analysis and moves toward the action orientation of most political economy authors.  However the model-making marxists, notably Bhaduri and Bardhan, have ignored the need to analyse the change process and have instead appeared to see the system as perpetually reproducing itself.  Local non-governmental organisations (NGOs) are working on watershed development and natural resource management, and since the early 1990s they have begun to involve members in micro-credit groups.  However most of the NGO networks have weak links at the grass roots at present.  They could focus not only on income-generation and substitute credit sources, but also on the cultural, patriarchal, class, and caste bases of oppression in this region.  The case study suggests that strategies of the NGOs could perhaps be expanded to include a wide range of anti-oppressive activities.  Access to seaonal migrants would have to be focused during the farming season, or else visits to the works sites would be needed.  
       

    IV. Conclusion

    The prevailing contract system of Palamuuru labour can be analysed from within both marxist and neoclassical frameworks (Olsen, 1996).  While the marxists have tried to incorporate its exploitativeness into models, and to devise strategies for radical social transformation, the apolitical economists refuse to recognise unfreedom and oppression.  Some economists have even justified bondage by identifying reasons for workers to ‘freely choose’ this condition (Srinivasan, 1989).  

    Interlocking of markets has received attention elsewhere in the literature.  It has been argued that landlords’ interlinkages can reduce the accumulation of capital on the part of producers, leading to retarded growth (Bhaduri, 1973, 1983).  The intermediaries in the Palamuuru labour case display a reactionary character by fixing a contract wage less than subsistence level, trapping the labourer in debt bondage.  However we cannot say that this form of bondage is restricting the development of capitalism, when the labourers are creating infrastructure which can be seen as future means of production (e.g. roads; dams both for power and for irrigation).  The rate of exploitation, direct and indirect, is high since intermediaries pay a wage much lower than urban market wages and extract considerable unpaid overtime and child labour.  Yet the exploitation may draw complicity from the labourer whose terms of contract resemble those of co-existing and pre-existing attached labour relationships in the region.  We would argue that in addition to being exploitative and parasitic on the hard work of labourers, the intermediaries are also using traditional caste-based and patriarchal modes of oppression to maintain their exploitative labour relations.   

    Underneath the actions of the agents involved, we also have to look at the roles and identities that are internalised by workers.  Maistries and group maistries are seen as those who save the labourer in distress by offering work when otherwise they might starve.  Some lower-caste people who serve the landlords and employers think they will be rewarded with patronage during crises.  This patronage may at present consist only of loans which further bind the worker and the worker’s family.  It would be misleading to judge from some workers’ attitudes such as loyalty, dependence, devotion and submission that their bondage is completely self-chosen and voluntary.  On the contrary, studying local cases of resistance, resentment, and revolt would throw more light on the underlying compulsions as shown by Kapadia (1995) and by Lerche (1995).  This is an area for future research.  

    Organising labour in the light of the informal and interlocked nature of labour markets poses an extremely difficult task.  Migrant labourers are scattered and often travelling.  The eradication of bonded labour will need a multi-pronged strategy involving propaganda, legislation, mobilisation, rehabilitation, and some provision of basic amenities.  Any fragmented effort may fail. Isolated attempts to rehabilitate people have been failures.  Low wages, both for men and for women, themselves have to come under scrutiny, since the lack of independent subsistence is one reason why people accept bondage.  The state has tried three means to help such workers: the minimum wage laws, which are hardly ever implemented where local market wages lie below them; the employment guarantee programmes, which have not been enough to meet the needs of the masses; and the law abolishing bonded labour (dated 1976) which is still not effective.  A new strategy is needed.  

    The NGOs in the district have started women's education programmes which try to empower people to secure access to specific government relief programmes.  In particular, women are taught to approach authorities directly for seeking access to local employment schemes.  Our analysis has shown that the oppression that is linked to value-exploitation extends into family life, village rituals, traditions and norms of caste hierarchy, and thus is to some extent beyond the reach of the modern state.  The elimination of the parasitic middlemen’s role is part of the answer yet more fundamental changes are also needed.  In the process of struggle, any measures taken must recognise the past structural locations, the beliefs and values, and the embodied capabilities of workers, as well as the dyadic long-term relationships upon which some workers depend.  Nevertheless, there are prospects for change: 

     

    People starve: their survivors think in new ways about the market.  People are imprisoned: in prison they meditate in new ways about the law.  In the face of such general experiences old conceptual systems may crumble and new problematics insist upon their presence. (Thompson, 1978: 9)     


    Notes

    1.  We are grateful for comments received at the Conference of the Indian Political Economy Association, 1995, and at the Conference of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economics, 1994, on material presented here.  We also wish to thank D. Narasimha Reddy for his support regarding this work.  Finally, we are grateful to the advice of the anonymous reviewers regarding revision of the paper.   back to text  

    2.  "Manu, writing later than Koutilya, outlined only seven categories of dasas.  They are: persons captured in battle; those enslaved in return for food; dasas born in the house of the master; those who are bought; dasas inherited as part of patrimony; dasas who are given away by their parents; and persons enslaved for not paying a fine." See Chakravarthy (1985), 40.   back to text  

    3.  An account of various colonial laws is given by Dingwaney (1985) in Patnaik and Dingwaney, eds. (1985), 340-50.   back to text  

    4.  One example illustrating the gender bias implicit in ungendered analyses of ‘workers’ is van der Linden’s analysis of employers’ and employees’ strategic choices regarding employment relations.  Van der Linden glosses over gender differences and possible additional sources of control or oppression facing women, relative to men.  Van der Linden presents an idealised model of employers’ motives and employees’ motives.  His use of s/he as the pronoun for employers here does not resolve the problem of having a fundamentally ungendered analysis at this point (1998: 516-519). 
    back to text  

    5.  Studies such as Kapadia (1995) and Lerche (1995) diverge from the pattern set by Bhaduri (1983) and Miles (1987).   back to text  

    6.  Mahabubnagar was earlier known as Palamuuru.  It was renamed after the erstwhile ruler, the 6th Nizam, Mir Mahabubali Khan in 1929, but people still call it informally by its old name, and the migrant labourers are referred to as Palamuuru labour.  The district was under autonomous kingdoms (Samsthanams), and administratively and politically the region remained isolated and insulated from the famous Telangana Peasant armed revolt of 1947.   back to text  

    7.  The Report on Indebtedness in Nizam Domain (1934) mentioned that the district was under severe drought, near famine conditions, with loss of cattle and subsequent indebtedness among farmers.  
    back to text 
     

    8. "The construction of Nizamsagar dam involved a massive need for labour both skilled and unskilled.  Especially excavation of earth, blasting, blasting rock in foundation, quarrying stone for machinery and miscellaneous.  The labour for these works had been imported from dominions including Raichur, Gulbarga, Mahabubnagar, Nalgonda and Karimnagar...Palmuuries coming from Mahabubnagar did a good work at excavation, especially earth work at ground level...The method of recruiting the labourers is mainly through the department by forwarding advances ranging from Rs. 5 to Rs. 10 per year for the gangs willing to come." The Report on the History of Nizamsagar Project, Hyderabad, Deccan, Public works Dept., H.E.H.Nizam Dominion, 1939 (A.P.Archives, Hyderabad).   back to text  

    9.  The use of the male gender here is important empirically because (a) one cannot study female supervisors, so can only comment on male supervisors; and (b) the gendering of supervision may give hints to future researchers on why the system perpetuates itself so repeatedly.  Life histories, family case studies, or critical incident analysis may be needed to examine why men turn to this particular activity and how these men interact with the large contractors in ways that ultimately exploit both men and women.  The present study has more limited aims and did not use in-depth qualitative methods. back to text  

    10.  At the rate of 4 hours per day of extra-labour, there are 112 days of unpaid work!  Taking 336 workdays per year multiplied by Rs. 35 daily wage (Hyderabad construction industry wage at that time) the sum is Rs. 11,820.  Assuming an absence of 30 days in that period, the labourer is still entitled to Rs. 10,710.   back to text  

    11.  The public works department while calling for tenders on construction work gives a rough cost of production, which includes provision of market wages.  The lowest bidder is given the contract and there is nobody to check on what is actually paid.  The construction companies find it advantageous to rely on the middlemen for various reasons such as easy mobilisation and few direct management problems—it’s the maestry’s headache and the company can save a phenomenal amount of money by underpayment.  The labour supply is not only assured for the present but also for the future.  
    back to text  

    12.  By contrast the statutory minimum wages for agricultural labour tasks over this period were all less than Rs. 20 per day.   back to text  

    13.  According to the Bonded Labour Abolition Act, a person is presumed to have entered into the contract in consideration of i) advance of money by the person/ascendants/descendants from the employer, or ii) in consideration of being born a certain caste, or...for a specified/unspecified period of time, based on oral or written contract.  Bonded Labour Abolition Act 1976, Labour Year Book, Labour Bureau. Shimla. 1-5.  See also Brass (1997b: 42) for a review of what he calls India’s ‘law-as-rhetoric’.   back to text  

    14.  From field data collected by Ramana Murthy in 1991 and 1994.    back to text  

    15.  Given the subsistence nature of the local agriculture, these gross farm incomes had to be estimated from information on the yield and acreage of respondents’ fields, after deducting the imputed cost of reported purchased inputs.  Net incomes were also calculated by deducting imputed values of family labour, using an estimated 1991 local wage rate of Rs. 10 per day for all.  Actual wages vary according to the sex and age of worker, and by task, but this minimal figure was used as a rough estimate’.    back to text  

    16.  In Telugu the word for famine also means drought (karuvu).   back to text  

    17.  From field data collected by Ramana Murthy in 1991 and 1994.    back to text  

    18.  From field data collected by Ramana Murthy in 1991 and 1994.    back to text  

    19.  From field data collected by Ramana Murthy in 1991 and 1994.    back to text  

    20.  From field data collected by Ramana Murthy in 1991 and 1994.    back to text  

    21.  From field data collected by Ramana Murthy in 1991 and 1994.    back to text  

    22.  From field data collected by Ramana Murthy in 1991 and 1994.    back to text  



    Sources

    Agarwal, Bina. (1998). "Disinherited Peasants, Disadvantaged Workers: A Gender Perspective on Land and Livelihood," in Economic and Political Weekly. 28 March. Vol. 33, No. 13. A2-A28.  
    back to text 
     

    Bagchi, A.K. (1975). "Relation of Agriculture to Industry in the Context of South Asia," in Frontier. Autumn. 22-24.  

    Balagopal, K. (1988). Probings in the Political Economy of Agrarian Classes and Conflicts. Hyderabad: Perspectives Press.   back to text  

    Bandyopadyaya. (1976). "Vettichakiri in M.K.," in National Labour Institute Bulletin. No. 2 (3).  

    Bardhan, P. K., ed. (1989). The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions. Oxford: Clarendon Press.  

    Barucha, S.M. (1937). Agricultural Indebtedness in H.E.H. Nizam Dominion. Hyderabad: Andhra Pradesh Archives.  

    Basu, Kaushik. (1983). "The Emergence of Isolation and Interlinkage in Rural Markets," Oxford Economic Papers. No. 35. 262-280.   back to text  

    Basu, Kaushik. (1986). "One Kind of Power," Oxford Economic Papers. No. 38. 259-282. 
    back to text  

    Bhaduri, Amit. (1973). "A Study in Agricultural Backwardness Under Semi-Feudalism," in Economic Journal. March. 120-37.   back to text  

    Bhaduri, Amit. (1983). The Economic Structure of Backward Agriculture. Delhi: Macmillan. 
    back to text  

    Bhaduri, Amit. (1986). "Forced Commerce and Agrarian Growth," in World Development. 14:2. 267-272.  

    Bhaduri, A. (1977). "On the Formation of Usurious Interest Rates in Backward Agriculture," in Cambridge Journal of Economics. No. 1. 341-352.   back to text  

    Bhalla, A.S., et al, eds. (1993). Images of Rural India in Twentieth Century. Delhi: Oxford University Press.  

    Bharadwaj, Krishna. (1985). "A View on Commercialisation in Indian Agriculture and Development of Capitalism," in Journal of Peasant Studies. Vol. 12, No. 4. 494-519.   back to text  

    Bharadwaj, Krishna, and P.K. Das. (1975). "Tenurial Conditions and Modes of Exploitation," in Economic and Political Weekly. June. Vol. 10. A49-55.  

    Brass, Tom. (1986). "The Elementary Strictures of Kinship: Unfree Relations and the Production of Commodities," in Social Analysis. No. 20.   back to text  

    Brass, Tom. (1990). "Class Struggle and Deproletarianisation of Agricultural Labour in Haryana (India)," in Journal of Peasant Studies. Vol. 18, No. 1. 36-67.   back to text  

    Brass, Tom. (1991). "Market Essentialism and the Impermissibility of Unfree Labour: A Reply to Shlomowitz," in Slavery and Abolition. Vol. 12, No. 3. 225-244.  

    Brass, Tom. (1995). "Unfree Labour and Agrarian Change: A Different View," in Economic and Political Weekly. 1 April. 697-699.   back to text  

    Brass, Tom. (1997a). "Some Observations on Unfree Labour, Capitalist Restructuring and Deproletarianisation," in Brass and van der Linden, eds. (1998). 57-76.   back to text  

    Brass, Tom. (1997b). "Introduction," in Brass and van der Linden, eds. (1998). 11-44.   back to text  

    Brass, Tom, and Henry Bernstein. (1992). "Introduction: Proletarianisation and Deproletarianisation on the Colonial Plantations," in Journal of Peasant Studies. 19. 1-40.   back to text  

    Brass, Tom, and Marcel van der Linden, eds. (1998). Free and Unfree Labour: The Debate Continues. Berlin and Paris: Peter Lang AG.   back to text  

    Breman, Jan. (1984). Of Peasants, Paupers and Migrants. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.  

    Chakravarty, U. (1985). "Of Dasas and Karmakaras: Servile Labour in Ancient India," in Patnaik and Dingwaney, eds. (1985). 35-75   back to text  

    Dingwaney, Manjari. (1985). "Unredeemed Promises: The Law and Servitude," in Patnaik and Dingwaney, eds. (1985). 283-347.  

    Fay, Brian. (1987). Critical Social Science: Liberation and its Limits. Oxford: Polity.   back to text  

    Government of Andhra Pradesh, Bureau of Economics and Statistics (various years). Handbook of Statistics, Mahabuubnagar District, Hyderabad.   back to text  

    Grossman, Jonathan. (1998). "The Right to Strike and Worker Freedom in and beyond Apartheid," in Brass and van der Linden, eds. (1998).   back to text  

    Harriss, J. (1982). Capitalism and Peasant Farming: Agrarian Structure and Ideology in Northern Tamil Nadu. Bombay.   back to text  

    Harriss-White, B. (1996). A Political Economy of Agricultural Markets in South India: Masters of the Countryside. New Delhi: Sage.   back to text  

    H.E.H. Nizam Dominion. (1939). The Report on the History of Nizamsagar Project. Hyderabad, Deccan, Public Works Department. (Andhra Pradesh Archives, Hyderabad).   back to text  

    Himmelweit, S. (1995). "The Discovery of ‘Unpaid Work’: The Social Consequences of the Expansion of ‘Work’," in Feminist Economics. Vol. 1, No. 2. 1-20.   back to text  

    Hjejle, Benedicte. (1967). "Slavery and Agricultural Bondage in South India in the Nineteenth Century," in Scandinavian Economic History Review. Vol. XI, Nos. 1-2.   back to text  

    Hodgson, Geoffrey. (1982). Capitalism, Value and Exploitation. London: Martin Robertson. 
    back to text  

    Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (1989). "Institutional Economic Theory: the Old Versus the New," in Review of Political Economy. Vol. 1, No. 3. 249-269. 

    Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (1993). "Institutional Economics: Surveying the 'Old' and the 'New'," in Economics and Evolution: Bringing Life Back into Economics. Cambridge, UK: Polity Press. Originally published in Metroeconomica. Vol. 44, No. 1, 1993. 1-28.   back to text  

    Hoff, K. and J. Stiglitz. (1990). "Imperfect Information and Rural Credit Markets: Puzzles and Policy Perspectives," in World Bank Economic Review. Vol. 4, No. 3. 235-250.   back to text  

    Jodhka, Surinder Singh. (1994). "Agrarian Change and Attached Labour: Emerging Patterns in Haryana Agriculture," in Economic and Political Weekly. 24 September. Vol. 29, No. 39.  
    back to text 
     

    Kabeer, N. (1994). Reversed Realities: Gender Hierarchies in Development Thought. London: Verso, and Delhi: Kali for Women.   back to text  

    Kalpagam, U. (1994). Labour & Gender: Survival in Urban India. Delhi: Sage.   back to text  

    Kapadia, Karen. (1992). "Every Blade of Green: Landless Women Labourers, Production and Reproduction in South India," in Indian Journal of Labour Economics. 35:3. 266-276.   back to text  

    Kapadia, Karen. (1995). "The Profitability of Bonded Labour: The Gem-Cutting Industry in Rural South India," in Journal of Peasant Studies. 22:3, April. 446-483.   back to text  

    Kerr, Ian J. (1998). "Free or Unfree? Railway Construction Labour in Nineteenth Century India," in Brass and van der Linden, eds. (1998).   back to text  

    Kosambi.D.D. (1956). "On the Development of Feudalism in India," in Journal of Bombay Branch of Royal Asiatic Society. 31/32. 258-69.   back to text  

    Krishnaiah, M. (1998). "Regular Farm Labour System in Semi-Arid Areas: Emerging Patterns in Andhra Pradesh," in Economic and Political Weekly. 28 March. A20-A28.  

    Kulke, Hermann, ed. (1997). The State in India 1000-1700. Delhi: Oxford University Press.  

    Kumar, Dharma. (1967). Labour and Caste in South India: Agriculture in Madras Presidency. London: Cambridge University Press.  

    Labour Bureau. "Bonded Labour Abolition Act 1976," in Labour Year Book. Shimla. 1-5.  

    Lerche, Jens. (1998). "Agricultural Labourers, the State and Agrarian Transition in Uttar Pradesh," in Economic and Political Weekly. 28 March. A29-A35.   back to text  

    Lerche, Jens. (1995). "Is Bonded Labour a Bound Category? Reconceptualising Agrarian Conflict in India," in Journal of Peasant Studies. 22:3, April. 484-515.   back to text  

    Miles, Robert. (1987). Capitalism and Unfree Labour: Anomaly or Necessity?. London: Tavistock.  back to text  

    Mohan Rao, J. (1999). "Agrarian Power and Unfree Labour," in Journal of Peasant Studies. 26: 2/3. 242-262.  

    Olsen, Wendy K. (1996). "Marxist and Neo-Classical Approaches to Unfree Labour in India," in Brass and van der Linden, eds. (1998). 379-404.   back to text  

    Olsen, Wendy K. (1998). "Paradigms in the Analysis of Credit Structures and Discourses in South Indian Banking," Working Paper No. 5, September. University of Bradford, Graduate School of Social Sciences and Humanities.   back to text  

    Patnaik, Utsa. (1983). Peasant Differetiation. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.   back to text  

    Patnaik, Utsa, and Manjari Dingwaney, eds. (1985). Chains of Servitude: Bondage and Slavery In India. New Delhi: Sangam Publishing.   back to text  

    Pradan, H.Pradhan. (1979). "Semi-feudalism: The Basic Constraints of Indian Agriculture," in Arvind N. Das and V. Nilkanth, eds. Agrarian Relations in India. New Delhi.  

    Prakash, Gyan. (1990). Bonded Histories: Genealogies of Labor Servitude in Colonial India. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.   back to text  

    Radhakrishna, R., et al. (1987). "A Study of Poverty Levels: Inter-District Analysis," Working Paper No. 431. Centre for Economic and Social Studies, Hyderabad.   back to text  

    Ramachandran, V.K. (1990). Wage Labour and Unfreedom: An Indian Case Study. Oxford: Oxford University Press.   back to text  

    Ramana Murthy, R. V. (1991). "Seasonal Labour Migration In Semi-Arid Areas: A Case Study of Palamuuru Labour," M.Phil. thesis, Department of Economics, University of Hyderabad. 
    back to text  

    Rammohan, C. (1987). Palamuuru Labour (Telugu). Hyderabad: VIRASAM (Revolutionary Writers Association).   

    Rao, R.S. (1995). Towards Understanding Semi-Feudal Semi-Colonial Society. Hyderabad: Perspectives Press. Series title: D. Narasimha Reddy, ed. Studies in Political Economy. Department of Economics, University of Hyderabad.   back to text  

    Rao, Usha. (1994). Palamoor Labour: A Study of Migrant Labour in Mahabubnagar District. C.D. Deshmukh Impact Centre, Council For Social Development, Hyderabad.   back to text  

    Ravinder, A. (1989). "Labour Migration: A Dimension of Poverty," unpublished M.Phil. thesis, Department of Economics, Osmania University, Hyderabad.   back to text  

    Reddy, D. Narasimha. (1990). Rural Migrant Labour in Andhra Pradesh. Report submitted to the National Commission on Rural Labour, Government of India.   back to text  

    Saradamoni, Kunjuleks. (1973). "Agrestic Servitude in Kerala in the Nineteenth Century Century," in Indian Economic and Social History Review. 371-385.   back to text  

    Saradamoni, Kunjuleks. (1980). Emergence of a Slave Caste: The Pulayyas of Kerala. New Delhi: People’s Publishing House.   back to text  

    Sarkar, T. (1985). "Bondage In Colonial Context," in Patnaik and Dingwaney, eds. (1985). 97-126.   back to text  

    Sharma, R.S. (1956). "The Origins of Feudalism in India (c.AD 400-650)," in JESHO. 1. 297-328.   

    Sinha, Shantha. (1993). "Changing Landlord-Labour Relationships," in Bhalla, A.S., et al, eds. (1993).   

    Srinivasan, T.N. (1989). "On Choice Among Creditors and Bonded Labour Contracts," in P. K. Bardhan, ed. (1989). 203-220.   back to text  

    Srivastava, Ravi. (1989). "Interlinked Modes of Exploitation in Indian Agriculture During Transition: A Case Study," in Journal of Peasant Studies. Vol. 16, No. 4. 493-522.   back to text  

    Standing, Guy. (1981). "Migration and Modes of Exploitation: Social Origins of Immobility and Mobility," in Journal of Peasant Studies. Vol. 8, No. 2. 173-211.   

    Stein, Burton. (1980). Peasant State and Society in Medieval in South India. Delhi: Oxford University Press.   

    Subrahmaniam, Rama Raju, and Thimma Reddy. (1994). Bonded Labour in Andhra Pradesh (A Study in Medak District). Hyderabad: Centre for Economic and Social Studies.   back to text  

    Thapar, Romila. (1960). A History of India - Vol. 1. Harmondsworth: Penguin.   

    Thompson, E.P. (1978). The Poverty of Theory and Other Essays. London: Merlin.   back to text  

    Unni, Jeemol. (1998). "Non-Agricultural Employment and Poverty in Rural India: A Review of Evidence," in Economic and Political Weekly. 28 March. A36-A44.   

    Venkateswarlu, D. (1997). Ph.D. Dissertation, Department of Political Science, University of Hyderabad.   back to text  

    Walker, T.S., and J.G. Ryan. (1990). Village and Household Economies in India's Semi-arid Tropics. Baltimore and London: Johns Hopkins University Press.   back to text      

     

a b c d e f g h i j k l m n o p q r s t u v w x y z


rhizome

*editorial *table of contents *the j_spot collective *call for submissions *
*contributors *manifesto *guestbook issue cover* home

 
j_spot online edition ISSN 1481 8 5842  

[ Social and Political Thought main page ]